Abstract
People deny health risks, invest too little in disease prevention, and are highly sensitive to the price of preventative health care, especially in developing countries. Moreover, private sector R&D spending on developing-country diseases is almost non-existent. To explain these empirical observations, I propose a model of motivated belief formation, in which an agent’s decision to engage in health risk denial balances the psychological benefits of reduced anxiety with the physical cost of underprevention. I use the model to study firms’ price-setting behaviour and incentive to innovate. I also show that tax-funded prevention subsidies are welfare enhancing.
Dokumententyp: | Paper |
---|---|
Keywords: | health risk denial, optimal expectations, motivated beliefs, disease prevention, self-protection |
Fakultät: | Volkswirtschaft > Munich Discussion Papers in Economics > Mikroökonomik
Volkswirtschaft > Munich Discussion Papers in Economics > Verhaltenswissenschaftliche Ökonomik |
Themengebiete: | 300 Sozialwissenschaften > 330 Wirtschaft |
JEL Classification: | D03, I15, I11, I18 |
URN: | urn:nbn:de:bvb:19-epub-38581-2 |
Sprache: | Englisch |
Dokumenten ID: | 38581 |
Datum der Veröffentlichung auf Open Access LMU: | 18. Mai 2017, 08:11 |
Letzte Änderungen: | 06. Nov. 2020, 10:31 |
Literaturliste: | Acemoglu, Daron and Joshua Linn, “Market Size in Innovation: Theory and Evidence from the Pharmaceutical Industry,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2004, 119 (3), 1049–1090. Akerlof, George A and William T Dickens, “The Economic Consequences of Cognitive Dissonance,” American Economic Review, June 1982, 72 (3), 307–19. Ashraf, N., J. Berry, and J.M. Shapiro, “Can Higher Prices Stimulate Product Use? Evidence from a Field Experiment in Zambia,” American Economic Review, 2010, 100 (5), 2383–2413. Banerjee, A. and E. Duflo, Poor Economics: A Radical Rethinking of the Way to Fight Global Poverty, Public Affairs, 2011. Bénabou, Roland, “Groupthink: Collective delusions in organizations and markets,”The Review of Economic Studies, 2013, 80 (2), 429–462. Bénabou, Roland and Jean Tirole, “Self-Confidence and Personal Motivation,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2002, 117 (3), pp. 871–915. Bénabou, Roland and Jean Tirole, “Mindful economics: The production, consumption, and value of beliefs,” The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2016, 30 (3), 141–164. Bridet, Luc and Peter Schwardmann, “Selling dreams: Endogenous overoptimism and collateral use in financial contracts,” Mimeo, 2016. Brunnermeier, Markus K. and Jonathan A. Parker, “Optimal Expectations,” American Economic Review, September 2005, 95 (4), 1092–1118. Brunnermeier, Markus K, Christian Gollier, and Jonathan A Parker, “Optimal Beliefs, Asset Prices, and the Preference for Skewed Returns,” The American Economic Review, 2007, 97 (2), 159–165. Caplin, Andrew and John Leahy, “Psychological Expected Utility Theory And Anticipatory Feelings,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, February 2001, 116 (1), 55–79. Caplin, Andrew and Kfir Eliaz, “AIDS policy and psychology: a mechanism-design approach.,” RAND Journal of Economics, 2003, 34 (4), 631 – 646. Carrillo, Juan D and Thomas Mariotti, “Strategic ignorance as a self-disciplining device,” The Review of Economic Studies, 2000, 67 (3), 529–544. Cohen, Jessica and Pascaline Dupas, “Free Distribution or Cost-Sharing? Evidence from a Randomized Malaria Prevention Experiment,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, February 2010, 125 (1), 1–45. Coutts, Alexander, “Testing Models of Belief Bias: An Experiment,” Available at SSRN 2647508, 2015. de la Rosa, Leonidas Enrique, “Overconfidence and moral hazard,” Games and Economic Behavior, 2011, 73 (2), 429 – 451. de Meza, David and Clive Southey, “The Borrower’s Curse: Optimism, Finance and Entrepreneurship,” Economic Journal, March 1996, 106 (435), 375–86. Dubois, Pierre, Olivier de Mouzon, Fiona Scott-Morton, and Paul Seabright, “Market size and pharmaceutical innovation,” The RAND Journal of Economics, 2015, 46 (4), 844–871. Duflo, E., P. Dupas, M. Kremer, and S. Sinei, “Education and HIV/AIDS Prevention,” World Bank Policy Research Working Paper No. 4024, 2006. Dunkle, K.L., R.K. Jewkes, H.C. Brown, M. Yoshihama, G.E. Gray, J.A. McIntyre, and S.D. Harlow, “Prevalence and patterns of gender-based violence and revictimization among women attending antenatal clinics in Soweto, South Africa,” American Journal of Epidemiology, 2004, 160 (3), 230. Dunkle, K.L., R.K. Jewkes, M. Nduna, J. Levin, N. Jama, N. Khuzwayo, M.P. Koss, and N. Duvvury, “Perpetration of partner violence and HIV risk behaviour among young men in the rural Eastern Cape, South Africa,” Aids, 2006, 20 (16), 2107. Dunning, David, Chip Heath, and Jerry M Suls, “Flawed self-assessment implications for health, education, and the workplace,” Psychological science in the public interest, 2004, 5 (3), 69–106. Dupas, P., “Health behavior in developing countries,” Annu. Rev. Econ., 2011, 3 (1), 425–449. Eil, D. and J.M. Rao, “The good news-bad news effect: Asymmetric processing of objective information about yourself,” American Economic Journal: Microeconomics, 2011, 3 (2), 114–138. Festinger, Leon, A theory of cognitive dissonance, Vol. 2, Stanford university press, 1962. Grebe, E. and N. Nattrass, “AIDS Conspiracy Beliefs and Unsafe Sex in Cape Town,” AIDS and Behavior, 2011, pp. 1–13. Green, E.C., D.T. Halperin, V. Nantulya, and J.A. Hogle, “Uganda’s HIV prevention success: the role of sexual behavior change and the national response,” AIDS and Behavior, 2006, 10 (4), 335–346. Janz, Nancy K and Marshall H Becker, “The health belief model: A decade later,” Health Education & Behavior, 1984, 11 (1), 1–47. Koszegi, Botond, “Health anxiety and patient behavior,” Journal of health economics, 2003, 22 (6), 1073–1084. Koszegi, Botond, “Emotional Agency,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 02 2006, 121 (1), 121–155. Kocher, Martin G, Michal Krawczyk, and Frans van Winden, “Let me dream on! Anticipatory emotions and preference for timing in lotteries,” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 2014, 98, 29–40. Kopczuk, Wojciech and Joel Slemrod, “Denial of death and economic behavior,” Advances in Theoretical Economics, 2005, 5 (1). Kremer, M. and E. Miguel, “The illusion of sustainability,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, 2007, 122 (3), 1007–1065. Kremer, Michael, “Pharmaceuticals and the developing world,” The Journal of Economic Perspectives, 2002, 16 (4), 67–90. Kunda, Ziva, “Motivated inference: Self-serving generation and evaluation of causal theories.,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 1987, 53 (4), 636. Kunda, Ziva, “The case for motivated reasoning.,” Psychological bulletin, 1990, 108 (3), 480. Landier, Augustin and David Thesmar, “Financial Contracting with Optimistic Entrepreneurs,” Review of Financial Studies, January 2009, 22 (1), 117–150. Lazarus, R.S., Stress and emotion: A new synthesis, Springer Publishing Company, 2006. Mayraz, Guy, “Wishful Thinking,” CEP Discussion Papers dp1092, Centre for Economic Performance, LSE November 2011. Mijovic-Prelec, Danica and Drazen Prelec, “Self-deception as self-signalling: a model and experimental evidence,” Philosophical Transactions of the Royal Society B: Biological Sciences, 2010, 365 (1538), 227–240. Miller, John M, Eline L Korenromp, Bernard L Nahlen, and Richard W Steketee, “Estimating the number of insecticide-treated nets required by African households to reach continent-wide malaria coverage targets,” Jama, 2007, 297 (20), 2241–2250. Mobius, Markus M., Muriel Niederle, Paul Niehaus, and Tanya S. Rosenblat, “Managing Self-Confidence: Theory and Experimental Evidence,” NBER Working Papers 17014, National Bureau of Economic Research, Inc May 2011. Oster, Emily, Ira Shoulson, and E. Ray Dorsey, “Optimal Expectations and Limited Medical Testing: Evidence from Huntington Disease.,” American Economic Review, 2013, 103 (2), 804 – 830. Pecoul, Bernard, Pierre Chirac, Patrice Trouiller, and Jacques Pinel, “Access to essential drugs in poor countries: a lost battle?,” Jama, 1999, 281 (4), 361–367. Pettifor, A.E., D.M. Measham, H.V. Rees, and N.S. Padian, “Sexual power and HIV risk, South Africa,” Emerging Infectious Diseases, 2004, 10 (11), 1996–2004. Quattrone, George A and Amos Tversky, “Causal versus diagnostic contingencies: On self-deception and on the voter’s illusion.,” Journal of Personality and Social Psychology, 1984, 46 (2), 237. Ringold, Debra Jones, “Boomerang effects in response to public health interventions: some unintended consequences in the alcoholic beverage market,” Journal of Consumer Policy, 2002, 25 (1), 27–63. Robinson, Thomas N and Joel D Killen, “Do cigarette warning labels reduce smoking?: paradoxical effects among adolescents,” Archives of pediatrics & adolescent medicine, 1997, 151 (3), 267–272. Rothschild, Michael and Joseph E Stiglitz, “Equilibrium in Competitive Insurance Markets: An Essay on the Economics of Imperfect Information,” The Quarterly Journal of Economics, November 1976, 90 (4), 630–49. Sandroni, Alvaro and Francesco Squintani, “A Survey on Overconfidence, Insurance and Self-Assessment Training Programs,” Unpublished report, 2004. Sandroni, Alvaro and Francesco Squintani, “Overconfidence, Insurance, and Paternalism,” The American Economic Review, December 2007, 97 (5), 1994–2004. Schwardmann, Peter and Joel van der Weele, “Deception and self-deception,” Tinbergen Institute Discussion Paper, TI 2016-012/I, 2016. Sloman, Steven A, Philip M Fernbach, and York Hagmayer, “Self-deception requires vagueness,” Cognition, 2010, 115 (2), 268–281. Spiegler, Ran, “On Two Points of View Regarding Revealed Preferences and Behavioral Economics,” in Andrew Caplin and Andrew Schotter, eds., The foundations of positive and normative economics: a handbook, Oxford University Press 2008. Spinnewijn, Johannes, “Insurance and Perceptions: How to Screen Optimists and Pessimists,” The Economic Journal, June 2013, 123 (569), 606–633. Stockman, Lauren J, Thea K Fischer, Michael Deming, Bagrey Ngwira, Cameron Bowie, Nigel Cunliffe, Joseph Bresee, and Robert E Quick, “Point-of-use water treatment and use among mothers in Malawi,” Emerging Infectious Diseases, 2007, 13 (7), 1077–1080. UNAIDS, Report on the global AIDS epidemic, Joint United Nations Programme on HIV/AIDS., 2008. UNAIDS/WHO, “AIDS epidemic update,” Joint United Nations Programme on HIV/AIDS. 2005. Walque, D. De, “How does the impact of an HIV/AIDS information campaign vary with educational attainment? Evidence from rural Uganda,” Journal of Development Economics, 2007, 84 (2), 686–714. Weinstein, Neil D, “Unrealistic optimism about susceptibility to health problems,” Journal of behavioral medicine, 1982, 5 (4), 441–460. Weinstein, Neil D, “Unrealistic optimism about susceptibility to health problems: Conclusions from a community-wide sample,” Journal of behavioral medicine, 1987, 10 (5), 481–500. |