Abstract
Supporters of left-wing parties typically put more emphasis on redistributive policies than right-wing voters. I investigate whether this difference in tolerating inequality is amplified by suspicious success — achievements that might arise from cheating. Using a laboratory experiment, I exogenously vary cheating opportunities for stakeholders who work on a real effort task and earn money according to their self-reported performances. An impartial spectator is able to redistribute the earnings between the stakeholders, albeit it is not possible to detect cheating. I find that the opportunity to cheat leads to different views on whether to accept inequality. Left-wing spectators substantially reduce inequality when cheating is possible, while the treatment has no significant effect on choices of right-wing spectators. Since neither differences in beliefs nor differences in norms about cheating can explain this finding, it seems to be driven by a difference in preferences. These results suggest that redistributive preferences will diverge even more once public awareness increases that inequality might be to a certain extent created by cheating.
Item Type: | Paper |
---|---|
Keywords: | Cheating, inequality, fairness, political preferences, redistribution |
Faculties: | Economics |
Subjects: | 300 Social sciences > 330 Economics |
JEL Classification: | C91, D63, D83, H23, H26 |
URN: | urn:nbn:de:bvb:19-epub-41998-8 |
Language: | English |
Item ID: | 41998 |
Date Deposited: | 11. Jan 2018, 07:33 |
Last Modified: | 04. Nov 2020, 13:17 |
References: | Abeler, J., Nosenzo, D. and Raymond, C. (2016). “Preferences for truth-telling.” CESifo Working Paper Series, No. 6087. Ai, C. and Norton, E. C. (2003). “Interaction terms in logit and probit models.” Economics Letters, 80(1), 123–129. Alesina, A. and Angeletos, G.-M. (2005). “Fairness and redistribution.” American Economic Review, 95 (4), 960–980. Alesina, A. and La Ferrara, E. (2005). “Preferences for redistribution in the land of opportunities.” Journal of Public Economics, 89(5), 897–931. Alesina, A., and Giuliano, P. (2011). “Preferences for redistribution.” In Handbook of Social Economics, 1, 93–131. Amsterdam: North-Holland. Alm°as, I., A. W. Cappelen and B. Tungodden (2016). “Cutthroat capitalism versus cuddly socialism: Are Americans more meritocratic and efficiency-seeking than Scandinavians?” Discussion Paper 18/2016, NHH Dept. of Economics. Andreoni, J. and Bernheim, B. D. (2009). “Social image and the 50–50 norm: A theoretical and experimental analysis of audience effects.” Econometrica, 77(5), 1607–1636. Brandts, J. and Charness, G. (2011). “The strategy versus the direct-response method: A first survey of experimental comparisons.” Experimental Economics, 14(3), 375–398. Bortolotti, S., Soraperra, I., Sutter, M. and Zoller, C. (2017). “Too lucky to be true: Fairness views under the shadow of cheating.” CESifo Working Paper Series, No. 6563. Camerer, C. F. and Fehr, E. (2004). “Measuring social norms and preferences using experimental games: A guide for social scientists.” In Foundations of human sociality: Economic experiments and ethnographic evidence from fifteen small-scale societies, edited by J. Henrich, R. Boyd, S. Bowles, C. Camerer, E. Fehr, and H. Gintis. Oxford University Press. Cappelen, A. W., C. Cappelen and B. Tungodden (2017). “False positives and false negatives in distributive choices.” Discussion Paper, mimeo. Cappelen, A. W., Fest, S., Sørensen, E. Ø. and Tungodden, B. (2016). “Choice and personal responsibility: What is a morally relevant choice?” Discussion Paper 27/2014, NHH Dept. of Economics. Cappelen, A. W., Konow, J., Sørensen, E. Ø. and Tungodden, B. (2013). “Just luck: An experimental study of risk-taking and fairness.” American Economic Review, 103(4), 1398–1413. Cappelen, A. W., Sørensen, E. Ø. and Tungodden, B. (2010). “Responsibility for what? Fairness and individual responsibility.” European Economic Review, 54(3), 429–441. Cohn, A., Fehr, E. and Mar´echal, M. A. (2014). “Business culture and dishonesty in the banking industry.” Nature, 516(7529), 86–89. Conrads, J. and Lotz, S. (2015). “The effect of communication channels on dishonest behavior.” Journal of Behavioral and Experimental Economics, 58, 88–93. Fehr, E. and Fischbacher, U. (2004). “Third-party punishment and social norms.” Evolution and Human Behavior, 25(2), 63–87. Fehr, E., Naef, M. and Schmidt, K. M. (2006). “Inequality aversion, efficiency, and maximin preferences in simple distribution experiments: Comment.” American Economic Review, 96(5), 1912–1917. Fehr, E. and Schmidt, K. M. (1999). “A theory of fairness, competition, and cooperation.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 114(3), 817–868. Fischbacher, U. (2007). “z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments.” Experimental Economics, 10(2), 171–178. Fischbacher, U. and F¨ollmi-Heusi, F. (2013). “Lies in disguise—an experimental study on cheating.” Journal of the European Economic Association, 11(3), 525–547. Fong, C. (2001). “Social preferences, self-interest, and the demand for redistribution.” Journal of Public Economics, 82(2), 225–246. Frohlich, N., Oppenheimer, J., Bond, P. and Boschman, I. (1984). “Beyond economic man: Altruism, egalitarianism, and difference maximizing.” Journal of Conflict Resolution, 28(1), 3–24. Gneezy, U. (2005). “Deception: The role of consequences.” American Economic Review, 95(1), 384–394. Greiner, B. (2015). “Subject pool recruitment procedures: Organizing experiments with ORSEE.” Journal of the Economic Science Association, 1(1), 114–125. Houser, D., List, J. A., Piovesan, M., Samek, A. and Winter, J. (2016). “Dishonesty: From parents to children.” European Economic Review, 82, 242–254. Jiang, T. (2013). “Cheating in mind games: The subtlety of rules matters.” Journal of Economic Behavior & Organization, 93, 328–336. Kirchler, E., Maciejovsky, B. and Schneider, F. (2003). “Everyday representations of tax avoidance, tax evasion, and tax flight: Do legal differences matter?” Journal of Economic Psychology, 24(4), 535–553. Konow, J. (2000). “Fair shares: Accountability and cognitive dissonance in allocation decisions.” American Economic Review, 90(4), 1072–1091. Krupka, E. L. and Weber, R. A. (2013). “Identifying social norms using coordination games: Why does dictator game sharing vary?” Journal of the European Economic Association, 11(3), 495–524. Kuziemko, I., M. I. Norton, E. Saez and Stantcheva, S. (2015). “How elastic are preferences for redistribution? Evidence from randomized survey experiments.” American Economic Review, 105(4), 1478–1508. Mazar, N., Amir, O. and Ariely, D. (2008). “The dishonesty of honest people: A theory of self-concept maintenance.” Journal of Marketing Research, 45(6), 633–644. Möllerström, J., Reme, B.-A. and Sørensen, E. Ø. (2015). “Luck, choice and responsibility — an experimental study of fairness views.” Journal of Public Economics, 131, 33–40. Pigors, M. and Rockenbach, B. (2016). “The competitive advantage of honesty.” European Economic Review, 89, 407–424. Piketty, T. (1995). “Social mobility and redistributive politics.” Quarterly Journal of Economics, 110(3), 551–584. Rabin, M. (1993). “Incorporating fairness into game theory and economics.” American Economic Review, 83(5), 1281–1302. Shalvi, S. and De Dreu, C. K. (2014). “Oxytocin promotes group-serving dishonesty.” Proceedings of the National Academy of Sciences, 111(15), 5503–5507. Van Lange, P. A., Bekkers, R., Chirumbolo, A. and Leone, L. (2012). “Are conservatives less likely to be prosocial than liberals? From games to ideology, political preferences and voting.” European Journal of Personality, 26(5), 461–473. Zucman, G. (2014). “Taxing across borders: Tracking personal wealth and corporate profits.” Journal of Economic Perspectives, 28(4), 121–148. |