Abstract
In recent decades, many firms offered more discretion to their employees, often increasing the productivity of effort but also leaving more opportunities for shirking. These “high-performance work systems” are difficult to understand in terms of standard moral hazard models. We show experimentally that complementarities between high effort discretion, rent-sharing, screening opportunities, and competition are important driving forces behind these new forms of work organization. We document in particular the endogenous emergence of two fundamentally distinct types of employment strategies. Employers either implement a control strategy, which consists of low effort discretion and little or no rent-sharing, or they implement a trust strategy, which stipulates high effort discretion and substantial rent-sharing. If employers cannot screen employees, the control strategy prevails, while the possibility of screening renders the trust strategy profitable. The introduction of competition substantially fosters the trust strategy, reduces market segmentation, and leads to large welfare gains for both employers and employees.
Item Type: | Paper |
---|---|
Form of publication: | Preprint |
Keywords: | job design, high-performance work systems, screening, reputation, competition, trust, control, social preferences, complementarities |
Faculties: | Economics Economics > Munich Discussion Papers in Economics Economics > Munich Discussion Papers in Economics > Labor Economics > Chairs > Seminar for Economic Theory |
Subjects: | 300 Social sciences > 300 Social sciences, sociology and anthropology 300 Social sciences > 330 Economics |
JEL Classification: | C91, D86 |
URN: | urn:nbn:de:bvb:19-epub-11312-2 |
Language: | English |
Item ID: | 11312 |
Date Deposited: | 18. Jan 2010, 21:11 |
Last Modified: | 04. Nov 2020, 18:15 |
References: | Appelbaum, Eileen, Thomas Bailey, Peter Berg, and Arne L. Kalleberg (2000), Manufacturing Advantage: Why High-Performance Work Systems Pay Off, Ithaca, N.Y. Baker, George, Robert Gibbons, and Kevin Murphy (1994), “Subjective Performance Measures in Optimal Incentive Contracts,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 109(4), 1125-56. Benabou, Roland, and Jean Tirole (2006), “Incentives and Prosocial Behavior,” American Economic Review, Vol. 96(5), 1652-78. Bolton, Gary, Elena Katok, and Axel Ockenfels (2004), “How Effective are Electronic Reputation Mechanisms? An Experimental Investigation,” Management Science, Vol. 50(11), 1587-602. Brown, Martin, Armin Falk, and Ernst Fehr (2004), “Relational Contracts and the Nature of Market Interactions,” Econometrica, Vol. 72(3), 747-80. Brown, Martin, and Christian Zehnder (2007), “Credit Registries, Relationship Banking and Loan Repayment,” Journal of Money, Credit and Banking, Vol. 39(8), 1883-918. Bulow, Jeremy I., and Lawrence H. Summers, (1986), “A Theory of Dual Labor Markets with Applications to Industrial Policy, Discrimination and Keynesian Unemployment,” Journal of Labor Economics, Vol. 4(3), 376-414. Cabral, Luis, and Ali Hortacsu (2006), “Dynamics of Seller Reputation: Theory and Evidence from eBay,” Journal of Industrial Economics, forthcoming. Cain, Glen G. (1976), “The Challenge of Segmented Labor Market Theories to Orthodox Theory: A Survey,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 14(4), 1215-57. Doeringer, P.B., and Michael J. Piore (1971), Internal Labor Markets and Manpower Analysis, Heath: Lexington, Mass. 38 Dufwenberg, Martin, and Georg Kirchsteiger (2004), “A Theory of Sequential Reciprocity,” Games and Economic Behavior, Vol. 47, 268-98. Edwards, R. C., M. Reich, and D. M. Gordon (1975), Labor Market Segmentation, D.C. Heath, Lexington. Ellingsen, Tore, and Magnus Johannesson (2008), “Pride and Prejudice: The Human Side of Incentive Theory,” American Economic Review, Vol. 98(3), 990-1008. Falk, Armin, and Urs Fischbacher (2006), “A Theory of Reciprocity,” Games and Economic Behavior, Vol. 54(2), 293-315. Falk, Armin, and Michael Kosfeld (2006), “The Hidden Costs of Control,” American Economic Review, Vol. 96(5), 1611-30. Fama, Eugene F. (1980), “Agency Problems and the Theory of the Firm,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 88, 288-307. Fehr, Ernst, Alexander Klein, and Klaus M. Schmidt (2007), “Fairness and Contract Design,” Econometrica, Vol. 75(1), 121-54. Fehr, Ernst, and Bettina Rockenbach (2003), “Detrimental Effects of Sanctions on Human Altruism,” Nature, Vol. 422, 137-40. Fehr, Ernst, and Klaus M. Schmidt (1999), “A Theory of Fairness, Competition, and Cooperation,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 114, 817-68. Fehr, Ernst, and Klaus M Schmidt (2006), “The Economics of Fairness, Reciprocity and Altruism - Experimental Evidence and New Theories,” in: Handbook on the Economics of Giving, Reciprocity and Altruism, Vol. 1, Serge-Christophe Kolm and Jean Mercier Ythier (ed.), Amsterdam: Elsevier, 615–91. Fischbacher, Urs (2007), “z-Tree: Zurich toolbox for ready-made economic experiments,” Experimental Economics, Vol. 10, 171-78. Frey, Bruno S. (1997), “On the relationship between intrinsic and extrinsic work motivation,” International Journal of Industrial Organization, Vol. 15, 427-39. Frey, Bruno S., and Reto Jegen (2001), “Motivation Crowding Theory,” Journal of Economic Surveys, Vol. 15, 589–611. Gneezy, Uri, and Aldo Rustichini (2000), “Pay Enough or Don't Pay at All,” Quarterly Journal of Economics, Vol. 115(3), 791-810. Green, Francis (2008), “Leeway for the loyal: A model of employee discretion,” British Journal of Industrial Relations, Vo. 46(1), 1-32. Greiner, Ben (2004), “An Online Recruitment System for Economic Experiments,” in: Forschung und wissenschaftliches Rechnen 2003, Kurt Kremer and Volker Macho (ed.), GWDG Bericht 63, Göttingen, Ges. für Wiss. Datenverarbeitung. Grossman, Sanford, and Oliver Hart (1983), “An Analysis of the Principal-Agent Problem,” Econometrica, Vol. 51(1), 7-46. Handel, Michael J., and David I. Levine (2004), “The Effects of New Work Practices on Workers,” Industrial Relations, Vol. 43(1), 1-43. Holmström, Bengt (1999), “Managerial Incentive Problems: A Dynamic Perspective,” Review of Economic Studies, Vol. 66, 169-82. Holmström, Bengt, and Paul Milgrom (1994), “The Firm as an Incentive System,” American Economic Review, Vol. 84(4), 972-91. Huck, Steffen, Gabriele K. Lünser, and Jean-Robert Tyran (2006), “Competition Fosters Trust,” CEPR Discussion Paper No. 6009. Ichniowski, Casey, Kathryn Shaw, and Giovanna Prennushi (1997), “The effects of human resource practices on manufacturing performance: A study of steel finishing lines,” American Economic Review, Vol. 87(3), 291-313. Ichniowski, Casey, and Kathryn Shaw (2003), “Beyond Incentive Pay: Insiders' Estimates of the Value of Complementary Human Resource Management Practices,” Journal of Economic Perspectives, Vol. 17(1), 155-80. Kandel, Eugene, and Edward Lazear (1992), “Peer Pressure and Partnerships,” Journal of Political Economy, Vol. 100(4), 801-17. Kreps, David, Paul Milgrom, John Roberts, and Robert Wilson (1982): “Rational Cooperation in the Finitely Repeated Prisoners’ Dilemma,” Journal of Economic Theory, Vol. 27(2), 245-52. Lawler, E.E. III, S.A. Mohrman, and G.E. Ledford (1995), Creating High Performance Organizations: Employee Involvement and Total Quality Management, Jossey-Bass, San Francisco, CA. MacDuffie, John Paul (1995), “Human Resource Bundles and Manufacturing Performance: Organizational Logic and Flexible Production Systems in the World Auto Industry,” Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 48(2), 197-221. MacLeod, Bentley (2007), “Reputations, Relationships and Contract Enforcement,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 45(3), 597-630. MacLeod, Bentley, and James Malcomson (1998), “Motivation and Markets,” American Economic Review, Vol. 88(3), S. 388 - 402. MacLeod, Bentley and Daniel Parent (1999), “Job Characteristics and the Form of Compensation,” Research in Labor Economics, Vol. 18, 177-242. McGregor, Douglas (1960), The Human Side of Enterprise, New York: McGraw Hill. Milgrom, Paul, and John Roberts (1990), “The Economics of Modern Manufacturing: Technology, Strategy and Organization,” American Economic Review, Vol.80 (3), 511- 28. Milgrom, Paul, and John Roberts (1995), “Complementarities and Fit: Strategy, Structure and Organizational Change in Manufacturing,” Journal of Accounting and Economics, Vol. 19(2-3), 179-208. Osterman, Paul (1994a), “How Common is Workplace Transformation and Who Adopts it?” Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 47(2), 173-88. Osterman, Paul (1994b), “Supervision, Discretion, and Work Organization,” American Economic Review, Vol. 84(2), 380-84. Osterman, Paul (2006), “The Wage Effects of High Performance Work Organization in Manufacturing,” Industrial and Labor Relations Review, Vol. 59(2), 187-204. Rabin, Matthew (1993), “Incorporating Fairness into Game Theory and Economics,” American Economic Review, Vol. 83, 1281-302. Rebitzer, James B. (1995), “Is there a trade-off between supervision and wages? An empirical test of efficiency wage theory,” Journal of Economic Behavior and Organization, Vol. 28, 107-29. Rosen, Sherwin (1987), “The theory of equalizing differences,” in: O. Ashenfelter & R. Layard (ed.), Handbook of Labor Economics, Edition 1, Vol. 1, Chapter 12, 641-92, Elsevier. Saint-Paul, Gilles (1997), Dual Labor Markets, Boston: MIT-Press. Sliwka, Dirk (2007), “Trust as a Signal of a Social Norm and the Hidden Costs of Incentive Schemes,” American Economic Review, Vol. 97(3), 999-1012. Sobel, Joel (2005), “Interdependent Preferences and Reciprocity,” Journal of Economic Literature, Vol. 43, 392–436. Walton, Richard E. (1984), “From control to commitment in the workplace,” Harvard Business Review, Vol. 63(2), 77-84. |
Available Versions of this Item
- Screening, Competition, and Job Design. (deposited 18. Jan 2010, 21:11) [Currently Displayed]